1.
summary
Amidst
the cacophony of opinions on economic globalization, there is a clear consensus
that the business corporation . specifically the transnational corporation (TNC)
. is the central actor: the primary shaper of the global economy.
The development of
companies with interests and activities located outside their home country was
part and parcel of the early development of an international economy. Most of that activity is generated by a much smaller number of very large TNCs: the top 100 (less than 0.2% of the total number of TNCs worldwide) accounted for 14% of the sales of foreign affiliates worldwide, 12% of their assets and 13% of their employment in 2002. (UNCTAD 2004: 9)
There
are what have come to be called global corporations. The reasons why business
firms extend their operations outside their home countries, and how they do that,
are complex and highly contingent on particular circumstances.
Despite
recent developments in TNC activity, much of their investment continues to be
market oriented.
A firm
may have reached saturation point in its domestic market (an issue clearly
related to the overall size of the national market). Increasing profitability
may well depend, therefore, on being able to expand its market beyond its home
territory.
The
geographical unevenness of markets is one major set of reasons why firms engage
in transnational investment. The second set of reasons derives from the fact
that the assets that firms need to produce and sell their products and services
are also geographically very unevenly distributed and, therefore, may need to
be exploited in situ.
Initially,
it was the attraction of cheap . and usually unorganized . labour that was the
primary attraction for firms in certain industries, such as textiles, garments,
footwear, toys and consumer electronics. The so-called 'New International
Division of Labour’.
There are two major ways in which firms develop transnational activities: one is through what is known as 'greenfield’ investment; the other is through engagement with other firms, through either merger and acquisition or some form of strategic collaboration.
Advocates of
strategic alliances claim that by cooperating, firms can combine their
capabilities in mutually beneficial ways.
Contrary to much
of the received wisdom on the global economy, place and geography still matter fundamentally in
the ways in which firms are produced and in how they behave. All business
firms, including the most
geographically extensive TNCs, are 'produced' through an intricate
process of embedding in which
the cognitive, cultural, social, political and economic characteristics of the national home base play a dominant part.
There
are inherent obstacles to convergence among social systems of production of
different societies, for where a system is at any one point in time is
influenced by its initial state.
By the
very nature of their dispread geographical spread across different political,
cultural and social environments.
In
addition to the question of a TNC’s organizational architecture there is the related, though not identical,
issue of the geographical configuration of its activities. Developments in
transportation and communications technologies, as well as in production
process technologies, have facilitated the transformation of the geographical
extent over which a TNC can separate out its different functions as well as
their precise geographical configuration.
Changes
to a firm’s
geographical configuration often occur as a result of the firm’s decision on what to produce for itself, in-house, and what to
externalize to independent suppliers. The geographical extent of such
transnational production networks is highly variable. In fact, few such networks
can be described as being truly ‘global’. A marked recent trend, however, is for such networks to have a
strong regional dimension, that is, networks organized on a multinational scale
of groups of contiguous markets (Rugman and Brain 2003).
There
is, in other words, a territorial asymmetry between the continuous territories
of states and the discontinuous territories of TNCs and this translates into
complex bargaining processes in which, contrary to much conventional wisdom, there
is no unambiguous and totally predictable outcome.
2.
opinion
The inequality
of globalization is related to the geographical inequality of economic
development. As long as the profit comes from buying and selling cheaply, relying
on the difference between production cost and selling price, capital accumulation
is bound to depend on the time and space difference of the production element
price or quality, as noted by Kartani Gojin. In other words, the time
difference between the labour's employment costs and the price of the produce
produced later by the labour force, or the geographical differences in
price/characteristics of labour, land, raw materials, funds, etc. Countries or
businesses are actively trying to create and maintain these differences, which
is one factor in the development of geographical inequality in the economy. For
example, in the 1960s and 1980s, the Korean nation tried to curb wage increases
through blatant labor oppression to keep low export prices, while import
barriers allowed local companies to profit exclusively from the domestic consumer
market. Thus, capitalistic globalization has a tendency to homogenize social,
cultural, political and economic conditions, as well as to promote
differentiation or maintain existing differentiation. What is actually
happening is therefore a mixture of Western culture/standard and local
culture/standard rather than unilateral globalization to meet Western
standards, and outside culture and culture are accepted and digested in a local
context.
Now,
given that differences between countries, regions and cultures are still
significant in this so-called era of globalization, we can see that there may
be other alternative time and space structures besides globalization, and there
will also be many different forms of globalization itself reflecting the unique
context of each country, region and culture. For example, in the U.S., which
places more importance on prices than quality of labor on industrial production
organizations and has strong influence on financial capital, the U.S. actively
pushed for overseas relocation of manufacturers and overseas investment of
financial capital, but in Japan, which places importance on quality of labor
and has strong influence on manufacturing industries, it is inevitable that it
will be more prudent to relocate manufacturing companies abroad. In Europe,
meanwhile, the above-mentioned multinational corporate strategy (production and
sale completed within national boundaries) seems to be quite dominant, rather
than the transnational corporate strategy. It can also be fully observed that
the reduction, de-regulation, investment liberalization, privatization and
market opening of state intervention, which is characterized by
neo-liberalistic globalization and called the so-called "global
standard," are not applied consistently. For example, in the U.S., the
government does not actively intervene or allow foreigners to easily privatize
industrial sectors that are strategically important (e.g., defense, information
and communication industries, etc.). Thus, globalization is the process of
transnational re-structuring of space and space in various forms.
After
all, neo-liberalistic globalization, the U.S. and its sympathetic powers,
transnational capital, and transnational governing bodies such as the World
Trade Organization, the International Monetary Fund and the World Bank are
described as one special political and economic project and strategy as a
result of restructuring under the market opening and "global
standard" that forces a small number of interests on weak countries as inevitable.
It is not just a given, an independent variable that explains our future
mechanically. Globalization is not inevitable and depends on struggle and
negotiation. Of course, because their power is so strong, it may seem as if
neoliberal globalization is inevitable in some ways. But it should be
remembered that what makes it seem all the more inevitable in a country of
considerable economic size like Korea is domestic politicians, bureaucrats and
capital who sympathize and cooperate with this particular logic of
globalization. So instead of just accepting the logic of politicians and
businesses that globalization benefits and if it doesn't, we should first
ponder who will benefit and who will lose.
No comments:
Post a Comment